Skip to main content

Volume III: Chapter 4. The Effect of the Turnover on the Rate of Profit

Volume III
Chapter 4. The Effect of the Turnover on the Rate of Profit
    • Notifications
    • Privacy
  • Project HomeCapital
  • Projects
  • Learn more about Manifold

Notes

Show the following:

  • Annotations
  • Resources
Search within:

Adjust appearance:

  • font
    Font style
  • color scheme
  • Margins
table of contents
  1. Contents
  2. Preface
  3. Part I. The Conversion of Surplus-Value into Profit and of the Rate of Surplus-Value into the Rate of Profit
    1. Chapter 1. Cost-Price and profit
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 2. The Rate of Profit
    3. Chapter 3. The Relation of the Rate of Profit to the Rate of Surplus-Value
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 4. The Effect of the Turnover on the Rate of Profit
    5. Chapter 5. Economy in the Employment of Constant Capital
      1. I. In General
      2. II. Savings In Labour Conditions At The Expense Of The Labourers.
      3. III. Economy In The Generation And Transmission Of Power, And In Buildings
      4. IV. Utilisation Of The Excretions Of Production
      5. V. Economy Through Inventions
      6. Notes
    6. Chapter 6. The Effect of Price Fluctuation
      1. I. Fluctuations in the Price of Raw Materials, and their Direct Effects on the Rate of Profit
      2. Experiments in corpore vili
      3. Notes
    7. Chapter 7. Supplementary Remarks
  4. Part II. Conversion of Profit into Average Profit
    1. Chapter 8. Different Compositions of Capitals in Different Branches of Production and Resulting Differences in Rates of Profit
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 9. Formation of a General Rate of Profit (Average Rate of Profit) and Transformation of the Values of Commodities into Prices of Production
    3. Chapter 10. Equalisation of the General Rate of Profit Through Competition. Market-Prices and Market-Values. Surplus-Profit
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 11. Effects of General Wage Fluctuations on Prices of Production
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 12. Supplementary Remarks
      1. I. Causes Implying a Change in the Price of Production
      2. II. Price of Production of Commodities of Average Composition
      3. III. The Capitalist's Grounds for Compensating
  5. Part III. The Law of the Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall
    1. Chapter 13. The Law As Such
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 14. Counteracting Influences
      1. I. INCREASING INTENSITY OF EXPLOITATION
      2. II. DEPRESSION OF WAGES BELOW THE VALUE OF LABOUR-POWER
      3. III. CHEAPENING OF ELEMENTS OF CONSTANT CAPITAL
      4. IV. RELATIVE OVER-POPULATION
      5. V. FOREIGN TRADE
      6. VI. THE INCREASE OF STOCK CAPITAL
      7. Notes
    3. Chapter 15. Exposition of the Internal Contradictions of the Law
      1. I. General
      2. II. Conflict Between Expansion Of Production And Production Of Surplus-Value
      3. III. Excess Capital And Excess Population
      4. IV. Supplementary Remarks
      5. Notes
  6. Part IV. Conversion of Commodity-Capital and Money-Capital into Commercial Capital and Money-Dealing Capital (Merchant's Capital)
    1. Chapter 16. Commercial Capital
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 17. Commercial Profit
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 18. The Turnover of Merchant's Capital. Prices.
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 19. Money-Dealing Capital
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 20. Historical Facts about Merchant's Capital
      1. Notes
  7. Part V. Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise. Interest-Bearing Capital
    1. Chapter 21. Interest-Bearing Capital
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 22. Division of Profit. Rate of Interest. Natural Rate of Interest.
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 23. Interest and Profit of Enterprise
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 24. Externalization of the Relations of Capital in the Form of Interest-Bearing Capital
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 25. Credit and Fictitious Capital
    6. Chapter 26. Accumulation of Money-Capital. Its Influence on the Interest Rate
      1. Notes
    7. Chapter 27. The Role of Credit in Capitalist Production
      1. Notes
    8. Chapter 28. Medium of Circulation and Capital; Views of Tooke and Fullarton
      1. Notes
    9. Chapter 29. Component Parts of Bank Capital
      1. Notes
    10. Chapter 30. Money-Capital and Real Capital. I.
      1. Notes
    11. Chapter 31. Money Capital and Real Capital. II.
      1. 1. TRANSFORMATION OF MONEY INTO LOAN CAPITAL
      2. 2. TRANSFORMATION OF CAPITAL OR REVENUE INTO MONEY THAT IS TRANSFORMED INTO LOAN CAPITAL
    12. Chapter 32. Money Capital and Real Capital. III.
      1. Notes
    13. Chapter 33. The Medium of Circulation in the Credit System
      1. Notes
    14. Chapter 34. The Currency Principle and the English Bank Legislation of 1844
    15. Chapter 35. Precious Metal and Rate of Exchange
      1. I. MOVEMENT OF THE GOLD RESERVE
      2. II. THE RATE OF EXCHANGE
      3. RATE OF EXCHANGE WITH ASIA
      4. ENGLAND'S BALANCE OF TRADE
      5. Notes
    16. Chapter 36. Pre-Capitalist Relationships
      1. Notes
  8. Part VI. Transformation of Surplus-Profit into Ground-Rent
    1. Chapter 37. Introduction
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 38. Differential Rent: General Remarks
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 39. First Form of Differential Rent (Differential Rent I)
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 40. Second Form of Differential Rent (Differential Rent II)
    5. Chapter 41. Differential Rent II. First Case: Constant Price of Production
    6. Chapter 42. Differential Rent II. Second Case: Falling Price of Production
      1. I. Productivity of the additional investment of capital remains the same.
      2. II. Decreasing rate of productivity of the additional capital.
      3. III. Rising rate of productivity of the additional capital.
      4. Notes
    7. Chapter 43. Differential Rent II. Third Case: Rising Price of Production
    8. Chapter 44. Differential Rent Also on the Worst Cultivated Soil
    9. Chapter 45. Absolute Ground-Rent
      1. Notes
    10. Chapter 46. Building Site Rent. Rent in Mining. Price of Land
      1. Notes
    11. Chapter 47. Genesis of Capitalist Ground-Rent
      1. I. Introductory Remarks
      2. II. Labour rent
      3. III. Rent In Kind
      4. IV. Money-Rent
      5. V. Métayage And Peasant Proprietorship Of Land Parcels
      6. Notes
  9. Part VII. Revenues and their Sources
    1. Chapter 48. The Trinity Formula
      1. I [48]
      2. II
      3. III
      4. Notes
    2. Chapter 49. Concerning the Analysis of the Process of Production
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 50. Illusions Created By Competition
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 51. Distribution Relations and Production Relations
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 52. Classes
      1. Notes
  10. Supplement by Frederick Engels
    1. Introduction
    2. Law of Value and Rate of Profit
    3. The Stock Exchange
  11. Engels’ Edition of the Third Volume of Capital and Marx’s Original Manuscript
    1. 1. Extant Knowledge of Engels’ Editing
    2. 2. An Overview of Engels’ Textual Modifications
    3. 3. Interpretatory Handicaps Caused by Engels’ Edition
    4. 4. Conclusions
    5. References
    6. Footnotes

Chapter 4. The Effect of the Turnover on the Rate of Profit

The effect of the turnover on the production of surplus-value, and consequently of profit, has been discussed in Book II. Briefly summarised it signifies that owing to the time span required for turnover, not all the capital can be employed all at once in production; some of the capital always lies idle, either in the form of money-capital, of raw material supplies, of finished but still unsold commodity-capital, or of outstanding claims; that the capital in active production, i.e., in the production and appropriation of surplus-value, is always short by this amount, and that the produced and appropriated surplus-value is always curtailed to the same extent. The shorter the period of turnover, the smaller this idle portion of capital as compared with the whole, and the larger, therefore, the appropriated surplus-value, provided other conditions remain the same.

It has already been shown in detail in Book II [English edition: Vol. II, pp. 293-98. — Ed.] how the quantity of produced surplus-value is augmented by reductions in the period of turnover, or of one of its two sections, in the time of production and the time of circulation. But since the rate of profit only expresses the relation of the produced quantity of surplus-value to the total capital employed in its production, it is evident that any such reduction increases the rate of profit. Whatever has been said earlier in Part II of Book II in regard to surplus-value, applies equally to profit and the rate of profit and needs no repetition here. We wish only to stress a few of the principal points.

The chief means of reducing the time of production is higher labour productivity, which is commonly called industrial progress. If this does not involve a simultaneous considerable increase in the outlay of total capital resulting from the installation of expensive machinery, etc., and thus a reduction of the rate of profit, which is calculated on the total capital, this rate must rise. And this is decidedly true in the case of many of the latest improvements in metallurgy and in the chemical industry. The recently discovered methods of producing iron and steel, such as the processes of Bessemer, Siemens, Gilchrist-Thomas, etc., cut to a minimum at relatively small costs the formerly arduous processes. The making of alizarin, a red dye-stuff extracted from coal-tar, requires but a few weeks, and this by means of already existing coal-tar dye-producing installations, to yield the same results which formerly required years. It took a year for the madder to mature, and it was customary to let the roots grow a few years more before they were processed.

The chief means of reducing the time of circulation is improved communications. The last fifty years have brought about a revolution in this field, comparable only with the industrial revolution of the latter half of the 18th century. On land the macadamised road has been displaced by the railway, on sea the slow and irregular sailing vessel has been pushed into the background by the rapid and dependable steamboat line, and the entire globe is being girdled by telegraph wires. The Suez Canal has fully opened East Asia and Australia to steamer traffic. The time of circulation of a shipment of commodities to East Asia, at least twelve months in 1847 (cf. Buch II, S. 235 [English edition: Karl Marx, Capital, Vol. II, pp. 251-52. — Ed.]), has now been reduced to almost as many weeks. The two large centres of the crises of 1825-57, America and India, have been brought from 70 to 90 per cent nearer to the European industrial countries by this revolution in transport, and have thereby lost a good deal of their explosive nature. The period of turnover of the total world commerce has been reduced to the same extent, and the efficacy of the capital involved in it has been more than doubled or trebled. It goes without saying that this has not been without effect on the rate of profit.

To single out the effect of the turnover of total capital on the rate of profit we must assume all other conditions of the capitals to be compared as equal. Aside from the rate of surplus-value and the working-day it is also notably the per cent composition which we must assume to be the same. Now let us take a capital A composed of 80c + 20v = 100 C, which makes two turnovers yearly at a rate of surplus-value of 100%. The annual product is then:

160c + 40v + 40s. However, to determine the rate of profit we do not calculate the 40s on the turned-over capital-value of 200, but on the advanced capital of 100, and thus obtain p' = 40%.

Now let us compare this with a capital B = 160c + 40v = 200 C, which has the same rate of surplus-value of 100%, but which is turned over only once a year. The annual product of this capital is, therefore, the same as that of A:

160c + 40v + 40s. But this time the 40s are to be calculated on an advance of capital amounting to 200, which yields a rate of profit of only 20%, or one-half that of A.

We find, then, that for capitals with an equal per cent composition, with equal rates of surplus-value and equal working-days, the rates of profit of the two capitals are related inversely as their periods of turnover. If either the composition, the rates of surplus-value, the working-day, or the wages, are unequal in the two compared cases, this would naturally produce further differences in the rates of profit; but these are independent of the turnover and, for this reason, do not concern us at this point. They have already been discussed in Chapter III.

The direct effect of a reduced period of turnover on the production of surplus-value, and consequently of profit, consists of an increased efficiency imparted thereby to the variable portion of capital, as shown in Book II, Chapter XVI, "The Turnover of Variable Capital". This chapter demonstrated that a variable capital of 500 turned over ten times a year produces as much surplus-value in this time as a variable capital of 5,000 with the same rate of surplus-value and the same wages, turned over just once a year.

Take capital I, consisting of 10,000 fixed capital whose annual depreciation is 10% = 1,000, of 500 circulating constant and 500 variable capital. Let the variable capital turn over ten times per year at a 100% rate of surplus-value. For the sake of simplicity we assume in all the following examples that the circulating constant capital is turned over in the same time as the variable, which is generally the case in practice. Then the product of one such period of turnover will be:

100c (depreciation) + 500c + 500v + 500s = 1,600

and the product of one entire year, with ten such turnovers, will be

1,000c (depreciation) + 5,000c + 5,000v + 5,000s = 16,000,
C = 11,000, s = 5,000, p' = 5,000/11,000 = 45 5/11 %.

Now let us take capital II: 9,000 fixed capital, 1,000 annual wear and tear, 1,000 circulating constant capital, 1,000 variable capital, 100% rate of surplus-value, 5 turnovers of variable capital per year. Then the product of each of the turnovers of the variable capital will be:

200c (depreciation) + 1,000c + 1,000v + 1,000s = 3,200,

and the total annual product after five turnovers:

1,000c (depreciation) + 5,000c + 5,000v + 5,000s = 16,000,
C = 11,000, s = 5,000, p' = 5,000/11,000 = 45 5/11 %

Further, take capital III with no fixed capital, 6,000 circulating constant capital and 5,000 variable capital. Let there be one turnover per year at a 100% rate of surplus-value. Then the total annual product is:

6,000c + 5,000v + 5,000s = 16,000,
C = 11,000, s = 5,000, p' = 5,000/11,000 = 45 5/11%.

In all the three cases we therefore have the same annual quantity of surplus-value = 5,000, and, since the total capital is likewise equal in all three cases, namely = 11,000, also the same rate of profit of 45 5/11%.

But should capital I have only 5 instead of 10 turnovers of its variable part per year, the result would be different. The product of one turnover would then be:

200c (depreciation) + 500c + 500v + 500s = 1,700.

And the annual product:

1,000c (depreciation) + 2,500c + 2,500v + 2,500s = 8,500,
C = 11,000, s = 2,500; p' = 2,500/11,000 = 22 8/11%.

The rate of profit has fallen one-half, because the period of turnover has doubled.

The quantity of surplus-value appropriated in one year is therefore equal to the quantity of surplus-value appropriated in one turnover of the variable capital multiplied by the number of such turnovers per year. Suppose we call the surplus-value, or profit, appropriated in one year S, the surplus-value appropriated in one period of turnover s, the number of turnovers of the variable capital in one year n, then S = sn, and the annual rate of surplus-value S' = s'n, as already demonstrated in Book II, Chapter XVI, I. [English edition: Vol. II, p. 305. — Ed.]

It goes without saying that the formula p' = s' (v/C) = s' v/(c + v) is correct only so long as the v in the numerator is the same as that in the denominator. In the denominator v stands for the entire portion of the total capital used on an average as variable capital for the payment of wages. The v of the numerator is primarily only determined by the fact that a certain quantity of surplus-value = s is produced and appropriated by it, whose relation to it s/v, is m', the rate of surplus-value. It is only along these lines that the formula p' = s/(c + v) is transformed into the other: p' = s' v/(c + v). The v of the numerator will now be more accurately determined by the fact that it must equal the v of the denominator, that is, the entire variable portion of capital C. In other words, the equation p' = (s/C) may be correctly transformed into the equation p' = s' v/(c + v) only if s stands for surplus-value produced in one turnover of the variable capital. Should s be only a portion of this surplus-value, then s = s'v is still correct, but this v is then smaller than the v in C = c + v, because it is smaller than the entire variable capital expended for wages. But should s stand for more than the surplus-value of one turnover of v, then a portion of this v, or perhaps the whole of it, serves twice, namely in the first and in the second turnover, and eventually in subsequent turnovers. The v which produces the surplus-value and represents the sum of all paid wages, is therefore greater than the v in c + v and the calculation falls into error.

To make the formula precise for the annual rate of profit, we must substitute the annual rate of surplus-value for the simple rate of surplus-value, that is, substitute S' or s'n for s'. In other words, we must multiply the rate of surplus-value s', or, what amounts to the same thing, the variable capital v contained in C, by n, the number of turnovers of this variable capital in one year. Thus we obtain p' = s'n (v/C), which is the formula for the annual rate of profit.

The amount of variable capital invested in his business is something the capitalist himself does not know in most cases. We have seen in Chapter VIII of Book II, and shall see further along, that the only essential distinction within his capital which impresses itself upon the capitalist is that of fixed and circulating capital. He takes money to pay wages from his cash-box containing the part of the circulating capital he has on hand in the form of money, so far as it is not deposited in a bank; he takes money from the same cash-box for raw and auxiliary materials, and credits both items to the same cash-account. And even if he should keep a separate account for wages, at the close of the year this would only show the sum paid out for this item, hence vn, but not the variable capital v itself. In order to ascertain this, he would have to make a special calculation, of which we propose here to give an illustration.

For this purpose we select the cotton spinnery of 10,000 mule spindles described in Book I (S. 209/201) [English edition: p. 219. — Ed.] and assume that the data given there for one week of April 1871, are in force during the whole year. The fixed capital incorporated in the machinery was £10,000. The circulating capital was not given. We assume it to have been £2,500. This is a rather high estimate, but justified by the assumption, which we must always make here, that no credit operations were effected, hence no permanent or temporary employment of other people's capital. The value of the weekly product was composed of £20 for depreciation of machinery, £358 circulating constant advanced capital (rent £6; cotton £342; coal, gas, oil, £10), £52 variable capital paid out for wages, and £80 surplus-value. Therefore,

20c (depreciation) + 358c + 52v + 80s = 510.

The weekly advance of circulating capital therefore was 358c + 52v = 410. In terms of per cent this was 87.3c + 12.7v. For the entire circulating capital of £2,500 this would be £2,182 constant and £318 variable capital. Since the total expenditure for wages in one year was 52 times £52, or £2,704, it follows that in a year the variable capital of £318 was turned over almost exactly 8½ times. The rate of surplus-value was 80/52 = 153 11/13. We calculate the rate of profit on the basis of these elements by inserting the above values in the formula p' = s'n (v/C) : s' = 153 11/13, n = 8½, v = 318, C = 12,500; hence:

p' = 153 11/13 × 8½ × 318/12,500 = 33.27%.

We test this by means of the simple formula p' = (s/C). The total annual surplus-value or profit amounts to 52 times £80, or £4,160, and this divided by the total capital of £12,500 gives us 33.28%, or almost an identical result. This is an abnormally high rate of profit, which may only be explained by extraordinarily favourable conditions of the moment (very low prices of cotton along with very high prices of yarn), and could certainly not have obtained throughout the year.

The s'n in the formula p' = s'n (v/C) stands, as has been said, for the thing called in Book II [English edition: Vol. II, p. 295. — Ed.] the annual rate of surplus-value. In the above case it is 153 11/13% multiplied by 8½ or in exact figures, 1,307 9/18%. Thus, if a certain Biedermann [Biedermann — Philistine. A pun, being also the name of the editor of the Deutsche Allgemeine Zeitung. — Ed.] was shocked by the abnormity of an annual rate of surplus-value of 1,000% used as an illustration in Book II, he will now perhaps be pacified by this annual rate of surplus-value of more than 1,300% taken from the living experience of Manchester. In times of greatest prosperity, such as we have not indeed seen for a long time, such a rate is by no means a rarity.

For that matter we have here an illustration of the actual composition of capital in modern large-scale industry. The total capital is broken up into £12,182 constant and £318 variable capital, a sum of £12,500. In terms of percent this is 97½c + 2½v = 100 C. Only one-fortieth of the total, but in more than an eight-fold annual turnover, serves for the payment of wages.

Since very few capitalists ever think of making calculations of this sort with reference to their own business, statistics is almost completely silent about the relation of the constant portion of the total social capital to its variable portion. Only the American census gives what is possible under modern conditions, namely the sum of wages paid in each line of business and the profits realised. Questionable as they may be, being based on the capitalist's own uncontrolled statements, they are nevertheless very valuable and the only records available to us on this subject. [In Europe we are far too delicate to expect such revelations from our major capitalists. — F.E.]


Table of Contents for Capital, Vol. III

Annotate

Next Chapter
Chapter 5. Economy in the Employment of Constant Capital
PreviousNext
Written: Karl Marx, 1863-1883, edited by Friedrick Engels and completed by him 11 years after Marx's death; Source: Institute of Marxism-Leninism, USSR, 1959; Publisher: International Publishers, NY, [n.d.] First Published: 1894; On-Line Version: Marx.org 1996, Marxists.org 1999; Transcribed: in 1996 by Hinrich Kuhls, Dave Walters and Zodiac, and by Tim Delaney and M. Griffin in 1999; HTML Markup: Zodiac 1996, Tim Delaney and M. Griffin in 1999; Proofed and Corrected: by Chris Clayton 2006-7, Mark Harris 2010; eBook prepared: by J Eduardo Brissos 2011.
Powered by Manifold Scholarship. Learn more at
Opens in new tab or windowmanifoldapp.org