Skip to main content

Volume III: Chapter 7. Supplementary Remarks

Volume III
Chapter 7. Supplementary Remarks
    • Notifications
    • Privacy
  • Project HomeCapital
  • Projects
  • Learn more about Manifold

Notes

Show the following:

  • Annotations
  • Resources
Search within:

Adjust appearance:

  • font
    Font style
  • color scheme
  • Margins
table of contents
  1. Contents
  2. Preface
  3. Part I. The Conversion of Surplus-Value into Profit and of the Rate of Surplus-Value into the Rate of Profit
    1. Chapter 1. Cost-Price and profit
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 2. The Rate of Profit
    3. Chapter 3. The Relation of the Rate of Profit to the Rate of Surplus-Value
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 4. The Effect of the Turnover on the Rate of Profit
    5. Chapter 5. Economy in the Employment of Constant Capital
      1. I. In General
      2. II. Savings In Labour Conditions At The Expense Of The Labourers.
      3. III. Economy In The Generation And Transmission Of Power, And In Buildings
      4. IV. Utilisation Of The Excretions Of Production
      5. V. Economy Through Inventions
      6. Notes
    6. Chapter 6. The Effect of Price Fluctuation
      1. I. Fluctuations in the Price of Raw Materials, and their Direct Effects on the Rate of Profit
      2. Experiments in corpore vili
      3. Notes
    7. Chapter 7. Supplementary Remarks
  4. Part II. Conversion of Profit into Average Profit
    1. Chapter 8. Different Compositions of Capitals in Different Branches of Production and Resulting Differences in Rates of Profit
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 9. Formation of a General Rate of Profit (Average Rate of Profit) and Transformation of the Values of Commodities into Prices of Production
    3. Chapter 10. Equalisation of the General Rate of Profit Through Competition. Market-Prices and Market-Values. Surplus-Profit
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 11. Effects of General Wage Fluctuations on Prices of Production
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 12. Supplementary Remarks
      1. I. Causes Implying a Change in the Price of Production
      2. II. Price of Production of Commodities of Average Composition
      3. III. The Capitalist's Grounds for Compensating
  5. Part III. The Law of the Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall
    1. Chapter 13. The Law As Such
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 14. Counteracting Influences
      1. I. INCREASING INTENSITY OF EXPLOITATION
      2. II. DEPRESSION OF WAGES BELOW THE VALUE OF LABOUR-POWER
      3. III. CHEAPENING OF ELEMENTS OF CONSTANT CAPITAL
      4. IV. RELATIVE OVER-POPULATION
      5. V. FOREIGN TRADE
      6. VI. THE INCREASE OF STOCK CAPITAL
      7. Notes
    3. Chapter 15. Exposition of the Internal Contradictions of the Law
      1. I. General
      2. II. Conflict Between Expansion Of Production And Production Of Surplus-Value
      3. III. Excess Capital And Excess Population
      4. IV. Supplementary Remarks
      5. Notes
  6. Part IV. Conversion of Commodity-Capital and Money-Capital into Commercial Capital and Money-Dealing Capital (Merchant's Capital)
    1. Chapter 16. Commercial Capital
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 17. Commercial Profit
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 18. The Turnover of Merchant's Capital. Prices.
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 19. Money-Dealing Capital
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 20. Historical Facts about Merchant's Capital
      1. Notes
  7. Part V. Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise. Interest-Bearing Capital
    1. Chapter 21. Interest-Bearing Capital
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 22. Division of Profit. Rate of Interest. Natural Rate of Interest.
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 23. Interest and Profit of Enterprise
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 24. Externalization of the Relations of Capital in the Form of Interest-Bearing Capital
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 25. Credit and Fictitious Capital
    6. Chapter 26. Accumulation of Money-Capital. Its Influence on the Interest Rate
      1. Notes
    7. Chapter 27. The Role of Credit in Capitalist Production
      1. Notes
    8. Chapter 28. Medium of Circulation and Capital; Views of Tooke and Fullarton
      1. Notes
    9. Chapter 29. Component Parts of Bank Capital
      1. Notes
    10. Chapter 30. Money-Capital and Real Capital. I.
      1. Notes
    11. Chapter 31. Money Capital and Real Capital. II.
      1. 1. TRANSFORMATION OF MONEY INTO LOAN CAPITAL
      2. 2. TRANSFORMATION OF CAPITAL OR REVENUE INTO MONEY THAT IS TRANSFORMED INTO LOAN CAPITAL
    12. Chapter 32. Money Capital and Real Capital. III.
      1. Notes
    13. Chapter 33. The Medium of Circulation in the Credit System
      1. Notes
    14. Chapter 34. The Currency Principle and the English Bank Legislation of 1844
    15. Chapter 35. Precious Metal and Rate of Exchange
      1. I. MOVEMENT OF THE GOLD RESERVE
      2. II. THE RATE OF EXCHANGE
      3. RATE OF EXCHANGE WITH ASIA
      4. ENGLAND'S BALANCE OF TRADE
      5. Notes
    16. Chapter 36. Pre-Capitalist Relationships
      1. Notes
  8. Part VI. Transformation of Surplus-Profit into Ground-Rent
    1. Chapter 37. Introduction
      1. Notes
    2. Chapter 38. Differential Rent: General Remarks
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 39. First Form of Differential Rent (Differential Rent I)
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 40. Second Form of Differential Rent (Differential Rent II)
    5. Chapter 41. Differential Rent II. First Case: Constant Price of Production
    6. Chapter 42. Differential Rent II. Second Case: Falling Price of Production
      1. I. Productivity of the additional investment of capital remains the same.
      2. II. Decreasing rate of productivity of the additional capital.
      3. III. Rising rate of productivity of the additional capital.
      4. Notes
    7. Chapter 43. Differential Rent II. Third Case: Rising Price of Production
    8. Chapter 44. Differential Rent Also on the Worst Cultivated Soil
    9. Chapter 45. Absolute Ground-Rent
      1. Notes
    10. Chapter 46. Building Site Rent. Rent in Mining. Price of Land
      1. Notes
    11. Chapter 47. Genesis of Capitalist Ground-Rent
      1. I. Introductory Remarks
      2. II. Labour rent
      3. III. Rent In Kind
      4. IV. Money-Rent
      5. V. Métayage And Peasant Proprietorship Of Land Parcels
      6. Notes
  9. Part VII. Revenues and their Sources
    1. Chapter 48. The Trinity Formula
      1. I [48]
      2. II
      3. III
      4. Notes
    2. Chapter 49. Concerning the Analysis of the Process of Production
      1. Notes
    3. Chapter 50. Illusions Created By Competition
      1. Notes
    4. Chapter 51. Distribution Relations and Production Relations
      1. Notes
    5. Chapter 52. Classes
      1. Notes
  10. Supplement by Frederick Engels
    1. Introduction
    2. Law of Value and Rate of Profit
    3. The Stock Exchange
  11. Engels’ Edition of the Third Volume of Capital and Marx’s Original Manuscript
    1. 1. Extant Knowledge of Engels’ Editing
    2. 2. An Overview of Engels’ Textual Modifications
    3. 3. Interpretatory Handicaps Caused by Engels’ Edition
    4. 4. Conclusions
    5. References
    6. Footnotes

Chapter 7. Supplementary Remarks

Suppose, as is assumed in this part, the amount of profit in any particular sphere of production equals the sum of the surplus-value produced by the total capital invested in that sphere. Even then the bourgeois will not consider his profit as identical with surplus-value, i. e., with unpaid surplus-labour, and, to be sure, for the following reasons:

1) In the process of circulation he forgets the process of production. He thinks that surplus-value is made when he realises the value of commodities, which includes realisation of their surplus-value. [A blank space which follows in the manuscript, indicates that Marx intended to dwell in greater detail on this point. – F. E.]

2) Assuming a uniform degree of exploitation, we have seen that regardless of all modifications originating in the credit system, regardless of the capitalists' efforts to outwit and cheat one another, and, lastly, regardless of any favourable choice of the market – the rate of profit may differ considerably, depending on the low or high prices of raw materials and the experience of the buyer, on the relative productivity, efficiency and cheapness of the machinery, on the greater or lesser efficiency of the aggregate arrangement in the various stages of the productive process, elimination of waste, the simplicity and efficiency of management and supervision, etc. In short, given the surplus-value for a certain variable capital, it still depends very much on the individual business acumen of the capitalist, or of his managers and salesmen, whether this same surplus-value is expressed in a greater or smaller rate of profit, and accordingly yields a greater or smaller amount of profit. Let the same surplus-value of £1,000, the product of £1,000 in wages, obtain in enterprise A for a constant capital of £9,000, and in enterprise B for £11,000. In case A we have p' = 1,000/10,000 or 10%. In case B we have p' = 1,000/12,000, or 8⅓%. The total capital produces relatively more profit in enterprise A than in B, because of a higher rate of profit, although the variable capital advanced in both cases = £1,000 and the surplus-value produced by each likewise = £1,000, so that in both cases there exists the same degree of exploitation of the same number of labourers. This difference in the presentation of the same mass of surplus-value, or the difference in the rates of profit, and therefore in the profit itself, while the exploitation of labour is the same, may also be due to other causes. Still, it may also be due wholly to a difference in the business acumen with which both establishments are run. And this circumstance misleads the capitalist, convinces him that his profits are not due to exploiting labour, but, at least in part, to other independent circumstances, and particularly his individual activity.


The analyses in this first part demonstrate the incorrectness of the view (Rodbertus [Sociale Briefe an von Kirchmann, Dritter Brief: Widerlegung der Ricardo'schen Lehre von der Grundrente und Begründung einer neuen Rententheorie, Berlin, 1851, S. 125. – Ed.]) according to which (as distinct from ground-rent, in which case, for example, the area of real estate remains the same and yet the rent rises) a change in the magnitude of an individual capital is supposed to have no influence on the ratio of profit to capital, and thus on the rate of profit, because if the mass of profit should grow, so does the mass of capital upon which it is calculated, and vice versa.

This is true only in two cases. First, when – assuming that all other circumstances, especially the rate of surplus-value, remain unchanged – there is a change in the value of that commodity which is a money-commodity. (The same occurs in a merely nominal change of value, the rise or fall of more tokens of value, other conditions being equal.) Let the total capital = £100, and the profit = £20, the rate of profit being = 20%. Should gold fall by half, or double, the same capital previously worth only £100, will be worth £200 if it falls and the profit will be worth £40, i. e., it will be expressed in so much money instead of the former £20; if it rises, the capital of £100 will be worth only £50, and the profit will be represented by a product, whose value will be £10. But in either case 200:40 = 50:10 = 100:20 = 20%. In all these examples there would, however, have been no actual change in the magnitude of capital-value, and only in the money-expression of the same value and the same surplus-value. For this reason s/C, or the rate of profit, could not be affected.

In the second case there is an actual change of magnitude in the value, but unaccompanied by a change in the ratio of v to c; in other words, with a constant rate of surplus-value the relation of capital invested in labour-power (variable capital considered as an index of the amount of labour-power set in motion) to the capital invested in means of production remains the same. Under these circumstances, no matter whether we have C, or nC, or C/n, e.g., 1,000, or 2,000, or 500, and the rate of profit being 20%, the profit = 200 in the first case, = 400 in the second, and = 100 in the third. But 200:1,000 = 400:2,000 = 100:500 = 20%. That is to say, the rate of profit is unchanged, because the composition of capital remains the same and is not affected by the change in magnitude. Therefore, an increase or decrease in the amount of profit shows merely an increase or decrease in the magnitude of the invested capital.

In the first case there is, therefore, but the appearance of a change in the magnitude of the employed capital, while in the second case there is an actual change in magnitude, but no change in the organic composition of the capital, i. e., in the relative proportions of its variable and constant portions. But with the exception of these two cases, a change in the magnitude of the employed capital is either the result of a preceding change in the value of one of its components, and therefore of a change in the relative magnitude of these components (as long as the surplus-value itself does not change with the variable capital); or, this change of magnitude (as in labour-processes on a large scale, introduction of new machinery, etc.) is the cause of a change in the relative magnitude of its two organic components. In all these cases, other circumstances remaining the same, a change in the magnitude of the employed capital must therefore be accompanied simultaneously by a change in the rate of profit.


A rise in the rate of profit is always due to a relative or absolute increase of the surplus-value in relation to its cost of production, i. e., to the advanced total capital, or to a decrease in the difference between the rate of profit and the rate of surplus-value.

Fluctuations in the rate of profit may occur irrespective of changes in the organic components of the capital, or of the absolute magnitude of the capital, through a rise or fall in the value of the fixed or circulating advanced capital caused by an increase or a reduction of the working-time required for its reproduction, this increase or reduction taking place independently of the already existing capital. The value of every commodity – thus also of the commodities making up the capital – is determined not by the necessary labour-time contained in it, but by the social labour-time required for its reproduction. This reproduction may take place under unfavourable or under propitious circumstances, distinct from the conditions of original production. If, under altered conditions, it takes double or, conversely, half the time, to reproduce the same material capital, and if the value of money remains unchanged, a capital formerly worth £100 would be worth £200, or £50 respectively. Should this appreciation or depreciation affect all parts of capital uniformly, then the profit would also be accordingly expressed in double, or half, the amount of money. But if it involves a change in the organic composition of the capital, if the ratio of the variable to the constant portion of capital rises or falls, then, other circumstances remaining the same, the rate of profit will rise with a relatively rising variable capital and fall with a relatively falling one. If only the money-value of the advanced capital rises or falls (in consequence of a change in the value of money), then the money-expression of the surplus-value rises, or falls, in the same proportion. The rate of profit remains unchanged.


Transcribed for the Internet by Hinrich Kuhls

Table of Contents for Capital, Vol. III

Annotate

Next Chapter
Part II. Conversion of Profit into Average Profit
PreviousNext
Written: Karl Marx, 1863-1883, edited by Friedrick Engels and completed by him 11 years after Marx's death; Source: Institute of Marxism-Leninism, USSR, 1959; Publisher: International Publishers, NY, [n.d.] First Published: 1894; On-Line Version: Marx.org 1996, Marxists.org 1999; Transcribed: in 1996 by Hinrich Kuhls, Dave Walters and Zodiac, and by Tim Delaney and M. Griffin in 1999; HTML Markup: Zodiac 1996, Tim Delaney and M. Griffin in 1999; Proofed and Corrected: by Chris Clayton 2006-7, Mark Harris 2010; eBook prepared: by J Eduardo Brissos 2011.
Powered by Manifold Scholarship. Learn more at
Opens in new tab or windowmanifoldapp.org