Skip to main content

Volume I: Chapter 18: Various Formula for the rate of Surplus-Value

Volume I
Chapter 18: Various Formula for the rate of Surplus-Value
    • Notifications
    • Privacy
  • Project HomeCapital
  • Projects
  • Learn more about Manifold

Notes

Show the following:

  • Annotations
  • Resources
Search within:

Adjust appearance:

  • font
    Font style
  • color scheme
  • Margins
table of contents
  1. Contents
  2. Prefaces
    1. Preface to the First German Edition (Marx, 1867)
    2. Preface to the French Edition (Marx, 1872)
    3. Afterword to the Second German Edition (1873)
    4. Afterword to the French Edition (1875)
    5. Preface to the Third German Edition (1883)
    6. Preface to the English Edition (Engels, 1886)
    7. Preface to the Fourth German Edition (Engels, 1890)
  3. Part 1: Commodities and Money
    1. Chapter 1: Commodities
    2. Chapter 2: Exchange
    3. Chapter 3: Money, Or the Circulation of Commodities
  4. Part 2: Transformation of Money into Capital
    1. Chapter 4: The General Formula for Capital
    2. Chapter 5: Contradictions in the General Formula of Capital
    3. Chapter 6: The Buying and Selling of Labour-Power
  5. Part 3: The Production of Absolute Surplus-Value
    1. Chapter 7: The Labour-Process and the Process of Producing Surplus-Value
    2. Chapter 8: Constant Capital and Variable Capital
    3. Chapter 9: The Rate of Surplus-Value
    4. Chapter 10: The Working day
    5. Chapter 11: Rate and Mass of Surplus-Value
  6. Part 4: Production of Relative Surplus-Value
    1. Chapter 12: The Concept of Relative Surplus-Value
    2. Chapter 13: Co-operation
    3. Chapter 14: Division of Labour and Manufacture
    4. Chapter 15: Machinery and Modern Industry
  7. Part 5: Production of Absolute and Relative Surplus-Value
    1. Chapter 16: Absolute and Relative Surplus-Value
    2. Chapter 17: Changes of Magnitude in the Price of Labour-Power and in Surplus-Value
    3. Chapter 18: Various Formula for the rate of Surplus-Value
  8. Part 6: Wages
    1. Chapter 19: The Transformation of the Value (and Respective Price) of Labour-Power into Wages
    2. Chapter 20: Time-Wages
    3. Chapter 21: Piece Wages
    4. Chapter 22: National Differences of Wages
  9. Part 7: The Accumulation of Capital
    1. Chapter 23: Simple Reproduction
    2. Chapter 24: Conversion of Surplus-Value into Capital
    3. Chapter 25: The General Law of Capitalist Accumulation
  10. Part 8: Primitive Accumulation
    1. Chapter 26: The Secret of Primitive Accumulation
    2. Chapter 27: Expropriation of the Agricultural Population From the Land
    3. Chapter 28: Bloody Legislation Against the Expropriated, from the End of the 15th Century. Forcing Down of Wages by Acts of Parliament
    4. Chapter 29: Genesis of the Capitalist Farmer
    5. Chapter 30: Reaction of the Agricultural Revolution on Industry. Creation of the Home-Market for Industrial Capital
    6. Chapter 31: The Genesis of the Industrial Capitalist
    7. Chapter 32: Historical Tendency of Capitalist Accumulation
    8. Chapter 33: The Modern Theory of Colonisation1

Chapter 18: Various Formula for the Rate of Surplus-Value

We have seen that the rate of surplus-value is represented by the following formulae:

I.

Surplus-value

(

s

)

=

Surplus-value

=

Surplus-labour

Variable Capital

v

Value of labour-power

Necessary labour

The two first of these formulae represent, as a ratio of values, that which, in the third, is represented as a ratio of the times during which those values are produced. These formulae, supplementary the one to the other, are rigorously definite and correct. We therefore find them substantially, but not consciously, worked out in classical Political Economy. There we meet with the following derivative formulae.

II.

Surplus-labour

 

 

 

=

Surplus-value

=

Surplus-product

Working day

 

Value of the Product

Total Product

One and the same ratio is here expressed as a ratio of labour-times, of the values in which those labour-times are embodied, and of the products in which those values exist. It is of course understood that, by “Value of the Product,” is meant only the value newly created in a working day, the constant part of the value of the product being excluded.

In all of these formulae (II.), the actual degree of exploitation of labour, or the rate of surplus-value, is falsely expressed. Let the working day be 12 hours. Then, making the same assumptions as in former instances, the real degree of exploitation of labour will be represented in the following proportions.

6 hours surplus-labour

=

Surplus-value of 3 sh.

= 100%

6 hours necessary labour

Variable Capital of 3 sh.

From formulae II. we get very differently,

6 hours surplus-labour

=

Surplus-value of 3 sh.

= 50%

Working day of 12 hours

Value created of 6 sh.

These derivative formulae express, in reality, only the proportion in which the working day, or the value produced by it, is divided between capitalist and labourer. If they are to be treated as direct expressions of the degree of self-expansion of capital, the following erroneous law would hold good: Surplus-labour or surplus-value can never reach 100%.1 Since the surplus-labour is only an aliquot part of the working day, or since surplus-value is only an aliquot part of the value created, the surplus-labour must necessarily be always less than the working day, or the surplus-value always less than the total value created. In order, however, to attain the ratio of 100:100 they must be equal. In order that the surplus-labour may absorb the whole day (i.e., an average day of any week or year), the necessary labour must sink to zero. But if the necessary labour vanish, so too does the surplus-labour, since it is only a function of the former. The ratio

Surplus-labour

or

Surplus-value

Working day

 

Value created

can therefore never reach the limit 100/100, still less rise to 100 + x/100. But not so the rate of surplus-value, the real degree of exploitation of labour. Take, e.g., the estimate of L. de Lavergne, according to which the English agricultural labourer gets only 1/4, the capitalist (farmer) on the other hand 3/4 of the product 2 or its value, apart from the question of how the booty is subsequently divided between the capitalist, the landlord, and others. According to this, this surplus-labour of the English agricultural labourer is to his necessary labour as 3:1, which gives a rate of exploitation of 300%.

The favorite method of treating the working day as constant in magnitude became, through the use of formulae II., a fixed usage, because in them surplus-labour is always compared with a working day of given length. The same holds good when the repartition of the value produced is exclusively kept in sight. The working day that has already been realized in given value, must necessarily be a day of given length.

The habit of representing surplus-value and value of labour-power as fractions of the value created – a habit that originates in the capitalist mode of production itself, and whose import will hereafter be disclosed – conceals the very transaction that characterizes capital, namely the exchange of variable capital for living labour-power, and the consequent exclusion of the labourer from the product. Instead of the real fact, we have false semblance of an association, in which labourer and capitalist divide the product in proportion to the different elements which they respectively contribute towards its formation.3

Moreover, the formulae II. can at any time be reconverted into formulae I. If, for instance, we have

Surplus-labour of 6 hours

Working day of 12 hours

then the necessary labour-time being 12 hours less the surplus-labour of 6 hours, we get the following result,

Surplus-labour of 6 hours

=

100

Necessary labour of 6 hours

100

There is a third formula which I have occasionally already anticipated; it is

III.

Surplus-value

=

Surplus-labour

=

Unpaid labour

Value of labour-power

Necessary labour

Paid labour

After the investigations we have given above, it is no longer possible to be misled, by the formula

Unpaid labour,

Paid labour

into concluding, that the capitalist pays for labour and not for labour-power. This formula is only a popular expression for

Surplus-labour,

Necessary labour

The capitalist pays the value, so far as price coincides with value, of the labour-power, and receives in exchange the disposal of the living labour-power itself. His usufruct is spread over two periods. During one the labourer produces a value that is only equal to the value of his labour-power; he produces its equivalent. This the capitalist receives in return for his advance of the price of the labour-power, a product ready made in the market. During the other period, the period of surplus-labour, the usufruct of the labour-power creates a value for the capitalist, that costs him no equivalent.4 This expenditure of labour-power comes to him gratis. In this sense it is that surplus-labour can be called unpaid labour.

Capital, therefore, it not only, as Adam Smith says, the command over labour. It is essentially the command over unpaid labour. All surplus-value, whatever particular form (profit, interest, or rent), it may subsequently crystallize into, is in substance the materialisation of unpaid labour. The secret of the self-expansion of capital resolves itself into having the disposal of a definite quantity of other people’s unpaid labour.

Annotate

Next Chapter
Part 6: Wages
PreviousNext
First published: in German in 1867, English edition first published in 1887; Source: First English edition of 1887 (4th German edition changes included as indicated) with some modernisation of spelling; Publisher: Progress Publishers, Moscow, USSR; Translated: Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling, edited by Frederick Engels; Transcribed: Zodiac, Hinrich Kuhls, Allan Thurrott, Bill McDorman, Bert Schultz and Martha Gimenez (1995-1996); Proofed: by Andy Blunden and Chris Clayton (2008), Mark Harris (2010), Dave Allinson (2015).
Powered by Manifold Scholarship. Learn more at
Opens in new tab or windowmanifoldapp.org